Submitted by ICConline on
COMBINATIONS AND UNIONS IN THE NINETEENTH CENTURY
The following quotation illustrates how Marx summarised the main features of the process leading to the formation of the first workers’ organisations: “The first attempts of workers to associate among themselves always takes place in the form of combinations. Large-scale industry concentrates in one place a crowd of people unknown to one another. Competition divides their interests. But the maintenance of wages, this common interest that they have against their boss, unites them in a common thought of resistance – combination. Thus combination always has a double aim, that of stopping competition between workers, so that they can carry on general competition with the capitalist. If the first aim of resistance was merely the maintenance of wages, combination at first isolated, constitute themselves into groups as the capitalists in their turn unite for the purpose of repression, and in the face of always united capital, the maintenance of the association becomes more necessary to them than that of wages. This is so true that English economists are amazed to see the workers’ sacrifice a good part of their wages in favour of associations, which, in the eyes of these economists, are established solely in favour of wages. In England they have not stopped at partial combinations which have no other objective than a passing strike, and which disappear with it. Permanent combinations have been formed, trades unions which serve as ramparts for the workers in their struggles with their employers”, (Marx, The Poverty of Philosophy, pp. 149-50).
Trade unions appeared therefore as permanent organisations of the class whose purpose was to facilitate
the organised resistance of the workers against capital. Products of economic
conditions and instruments of a basically economic conflict, they were not,
however, nor could they be (contrary to the assertions of the
anarcho-syndicalists and the reformists) ‘a-political’ organisations.
Everything that has to do with the government of the state is political. Because the bourgeois state is the guarantor and defender of the relations that link capital to labour, any resistance to such relations is inevitably to the state, and therefore, a political struggle. Thus immediately following the last passage we quoted, Marx adds: “In this struggle - a veritable civil war - all the elements necessary for the coming battle unite and develop. Once it has reached this point, association takes on a political character...Economic conditions had first transformed the mass of the people of the country into workers. The combination of capital has created for this mass a common situation, common interests. This mass is thus already a class as against capital, but not yet for itself…But the struggle of class against class is a political struggle…Do not say that social movement excludes political movement. There is never a political movement which is not at the same time social”, (Marx, The Poverty of Philosophy, pp. 150 and 152).
But if it is quite obvious that the class struggle of the
proletariat cannot help but bear a relationship to the government of the
state, and hence is inevitably political
in nature, we still have to find out what type of political struggle it is.
Indeed in the nineteenth century the historic reality of
capitalism in its full tide of expansion meant that the political struggle of
the proletariat could take place on two different levels: on the one hand the
struggle fought on the terrain of the bourgeois state itself for economic and
political reforms, and on the other
hand the preparation for revolutionary struggle, the destruction of the
bourgeois state and of the society engendering it.
THE STRUGGLE FOR REFORMS
The nineteenth century was the apogee of capitalism’s historically ascendant phase. The major economic powers extended capital’s domination, transforming the entire world in its own image. The English, French, American, and German capitalists invaded the world with their commodities, a world which offered ever-growing, and seemingly, inexhaustible markets for their production. It was the great era of imperialist expansion and industrial revolutions.
Within this historic framework, the amelioration of working class living conditions constituted objectively, not only a real possibility, but also in certain cases, a stimulant to capitalist development. Thus, for example, the victory won by the English working class in reducing working hours to ten hours per day in 1848, was a real gain for the working class (it was not immediately cancelled out by compulsory overtime), and it also provided a stimulus to the British economy. This is how Marx commented on this event in Wages, Price and Profit, illustrating the necessity and the possibility for economic reforms: “The official economists announced that ‘it would sound the death-knell of English industry’ (when the Ten-Hour Bill was obtained by the workers). They threatened a decrease of accumulation, rise of prices, loss of markets, stinting of production, consequent reaction upon wages, ultimate ruin. Well, what was the result? A rise in the money wages of the factory operatives, despite the curtailing of the working day, a great increase in the number of factory hands employed, a continuous fall in the prices of their products, a marvellous development in the productive powers of their labour, an unheard-of progressive expansion of the markets for their commodities”, (Marx, Wages, Price and Profit, Peking edition, pp. 13 and 14).
However the bourgeoisie never granted such reforms out of
its own inclination. Any concession to the proletariat was made in the first
place to the detriment of capitalist profit. Generally speaking it was only
after the capitalists were goaded into realising the beneficial results such
reforms produced (in terms of acting as a spur to capitalist growth) that they
began to understand that it was in their interest to grant the proletariat
reforms. It was, therefore, only as a result of implacable struggle that the
working class could wrest reforms from the ruling class. This was the nature of
the defensive struggles of the proletariat in the nineteenth century.
Moreover, in this period of free-trade, the bourgeoisie governed
through Parliament. Here the different factions of the ruling class really confronted each other and
decided on government policies. For the working class, the right of universal
suffrage constituted a real means of influencing the policies of the bourgeois
state through its representatives in Parliament. Not that bourgeois
Parliamentarians would make great cause with the specific demands coming from
the representatives of the workers’ organisations. Within the terrain of the
bourgeois state, the antagonism existing between the proletariat and the
bourgeoisie could only ever be favourable to the ruling class. But the
bourgeoisie in this epoch was still divided into more progressive and more
reactionary factions. The modern bourgeoisie was still fighting against the
representatives of the ruling class inherited from the old regime whose
economic power remained, and against the most backward factions of its own
class. In the words of The Communist
Manifesto: “The organisation of the
proletarians.... compels legislative recognition of particular interests of the
workers, by taking advantage of the divisions among the bourgeoisie itself”,
(Marx, The Communist Manifesto).
In this historic period then, the struggle for democratic political rights was a necessity for the proletariat. The winning of universal suffrage, the right to form combinations and the parliamentary struggle itself, were political manifestations of the class struggle and formed an inseparable corollary to the struggle and organisation of the unions. Unionism and parliamentarism were specific forms in which the necessity and possibility of reformist struggles in ascendant capitalism were expressed.
THE REVOLUTIONARY STRUGGLE
The struggle for reforms was only one aspect of the
proletarian struggle in the nineteenth century. The working class is an
exploited class and consequently no reform whatsoever can bring about its
emancipation. The deepest expression of proletarian struggle lives and
flourishes in its struggle for the destruction
of exploitation and not in its struggles to ameliorate its exploitation. “An oppressed class is the vital condition
for every society founded on the antagonisms of classes. The emancipation of
the oppressed class thus implies necessarily the creation of a new society”,
(Marx, The Poverty of Philosophy).
Also proletarian revolutionaries did not see in the struggle
for reforms the authentic perspective for the working class, nor even the form
of struggle which could act as the essential focus for its activity. Imprisoned within its own limitations,
the struggle for reforms could only result in the defence of exploitation
itself. It was no longer a step towards the definitive emancipation of the
working class but a new noose hanging round its neck. As much as Marx defended
the necessity for reformist struggles, he just as energetically denounced the reformist tendencies that were trying
to imprison the working class within that struggle, who “saw in the struggle for wages, only the struggle for wages” and
did not see it as a school of struggle where the class was forging the weapons
for its ultimate emancipation. He coined the term ‘parliamentary cretinism’ to
describe the tendency in the workers’ movement which tried to create illusions
in the possibilities of parliamentary struggle and put all their energies in
parliamentary activity.
On the subject of reformist struggles, the Manifesto stated: “Now and then the workers are victorious, but only for a time. The real
fruit of their battles lies, not in the immediate result, but in the
ever-expanding union of the workers” (Marx, The Communist Manifesto). And in Wages, Price and Profit, he noted: “At the same time, and quite apart from the general servitude involved
in the wages system, the working class ought not to exaggerate to themselves
the ultimate working of these every-day struggles. They ought not to forget
that they are fighting with effects, but not with the causes of those effects;
that they are retarding the downward movement, but not changing its direction;
that they are applying palliatives, not curing the malady. They ought, therefore,
not to be exclusively absorbed in these unavoidable guerrilla fights
incessantly springing up from the never-ceasing encroachments of capital or
changes in the market. They ought to understand that, with all the miseries it
imposes upon them, the present system simultaneously engenders the material
conditions and the social forms necessary for an economical reconstruction of
society. Instead of the conservative motto, ‘A fair day’s wage for a fair day’s
work!’ they ought to inscribe on their banner the revolutionary watchword, ‘Abolition of the wages system!’”,
(Marx, Wages, Price and Profit,
Peking edition, pp. 77-8).
Similarly, the Resolution passed by the 1st International
regarding the unions, stated: “The
immediate objective of the workers’ unions was always limited to the
necessities of every-day struggles, to expedients against the incessant
encroachments of capital, in a word, to questions about wages and hours of
work. This activity is not only legitimate but also necessary”, but: “...the unions are far too exclusively
occupied with local and immediate struggles against capital. They have not sufficiently
understood their power to act against the system of wage-slavery itself. They
have too often stood aside from the more generalised movements and political
struggles…Apart from their immediate task of reacting against the aggravating
manoeuvrings of capital, they must now act as organisational spearheads of the
working class for the great goal of its radical emancipation. They must assist
any social or political movement tending in this direction”, (Resolution on the Unions, their past,
present and future, 1st Congress of the International Working Men’s Association,
Geneva, 1866).
For revolutionaries in the nineteenth century, the
systematic struggle of the class to win reforms and limit capitalist
exploitation, and the understanding that this struggle was not an end in itself
but a moment in the global revolutionary struggle, were complementary. The
marxist workers’ parties which (parallel to the growing influence of the
unions) developed in the second half of the nineteenth century and later formed
the 2nd International, tended from the beginning not only to provide the
working class with representatives for the parliamentary struggle, but also
constituted the political driving force of the unions. It was these parties
which, in the face of all the sectional and local struggles of the class, put
forward the common interests of the whole proletariat as a global, historical,
revolutionary class.
The ephemeral associations of the early times became under
the union form permanent organisations, which in close collaboration with the
mass parliamentary parties and organised around the systematic and progressive
struggle for reforms, constituted the place where the proletariat was unified
and developed its class consciousness.
THE UNIONS DESTROYED BY REFORMISM
But the fact that capitalism was at the height of its ascendant
phase meant that its destruction by the communist revolution was not yet on
the historical agenda. With the expansion of the productive forces under the
aegis of capitalist relations of production and the success of the
parliamentary and trade unions struggles in obtaining real reforms favouring
the working class, the very idea of the communist revolution began to appear
as a long term, even unattainable goal.
The dangers inherent in unionism and parliamentarism that
Marx had denounced continued to develop and with the famous slogan “the end is nothing, the movement is
everything”, the workers’ movement was over run by reformism. The workers’
leaders, at one time the representatives of the working class pitted against
capitalist society, gradually became the representatives of capitalism working against the class. The trade union and
parliamentary bureaucracy tended more and more to dominate proletarian
organisations.
One of the clearest signs of this evolution was expressed in
the tendency for political struggles to be isolated from economic struggles.
While the party was coming to be thought of only as a parliamentary machine, so
attempts were being made to make the unions purely economic organisations.
Through the separation of the political from the economic element in
proletarian struggles, these organisations were being shaped for their
integration into the rungs of the capitalist state.
The revolutionary left within the 2nd International led a
daily battle against this general degeneration. Rosa Luxemburg, for example,
stated: “There are not two different
class struggles of the working class, an economic and a political one, but only
one class struggle, which aims at one and the same time at the limitation of
capitalist exploitation within bourgeois society, and at the abolition of
exploitation together with bourgeois society itself” (Rosa Luxemburg, The Mass Strike, the Political Party and the
Trade Unions).
But the left could not manage to stem the tide. With the
entry of capitalism into decadence the unions and parliamentary parties were
flung without difficulty into the camp of the bourgeoisie.